Friday, April 16, 2010

Tea Party History

With April 15th marking tax day and the Tea Party movement becoming more vociferous--but not necessarily more coherent--now might be a good time to discuss the historical and economic aspects of the Tea Act of 1773, which engendered the Boston Tea Party. Not only do modern-day Tea Partiers have their economics wrong, they have their history wrong, as well.
Great Britain imposed the Townshend duties in 1767 to recover some of their expenditures from the Seven Years War. These duties (or taxes) were levied on many goods imported by the colonies--glass, paper, paint pigments, and tea. These external duties (or tariffs), save for the one on tea, were all repealed by 1771.
Then in 1773, British Parliament passed the Tea Act. This was not, contrary to popular belief, an additional tax on imported tea. Rather it was a modification of the Navigation Acts--the laws that governed trade relations between England, the American colonies, and other relevant trading partners. The Navigation Acts stipulated that any product heading to the colonies, including tea, had to first pass through English ports, where it would be subject to an English tax. The Tea Act of 1773, however, allowed the English East India Company to directly export Indian tea to the colonies without having to be routed (and thus taxed) through British ports.
This act also had the effect of eliminating a lot of colonial middlemen--merchants and wholesalers, primarily--who profited greatly from the tea trade. Needless to say, the Tea Act reduced the incomes these individuals received. This, combined with the elimination of the tax levied on goods that passed through British ports, reduced the price of imported tea for the colonists. Since most colonists did not drink tea, this act had little economic effect on the average colonist. However, colonial merchants saw their economic position being undercut by British merchants who could now export tea to the colonies duty free thanks to the Tea Act. The Tea Act eliminated the need for colonial middlemen and reduced the price of tea by reducing tariffs.
Colonial merchants responded to what they rightly perceived as a threat to their main income source--managing the importing and exporting of goods--by organizing the Boston Tea Party. The party itself was small; only 30-40 merchants partook. It was short, as well; it only lasted three hours. Over $1 million (in 2008 dollars) of tea was dumped into Boston Harbor. British Parliament responded by further tightening its grip on colonial commerce by imposing the Intolerable Acts in 1774. (These acts were largely political in nature and had little to do with economics, hence the name.)
In summary, the Tea Act of 1773 eliminated taxes on imported tea. And the Boston Tea Party itself was led by wealthy, urban colonial merchants who saw their wealth destroyed due to the elimination if the tea tariff. In other words, modern-day Tea Partiers name their movement after a revolt led by wealthy urbanites (not "real" Americans) in response to a tax reduction. Just like their economics, Tea Partiers have their history wrong, as well.

Monday, April 12, 2010

Markets at work

Gotta love the work that "This American Life" is doing on the financial crisis:





Bet Against the American Dream from Alexander Hotz on Vimeo.

And for more on how this might work, from Ezra Klein's interpretation of a new paper called "Financial Innovation and Financial Fragility" (pdf), Nicola Gennaioli, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny:


... the game runs like this: Investors want to make more money with less risk. Someone invents a financial product that appears to make investors more money with less risk -- in this case, subprime securities. Demand for this new product explodes. But few understand this new product, and even the people who do understand the new product don't know how it performs under stress (it's a new product, after all). At the beginning, this actually helps the product: because its risks aren't known, they're ignored, and so it looks like a better deal than it is and sells more of itself than it should.
Then something bad happens. The new product shows its flaws. And precisely because no one really understands it, the market cracks. Investors all run away at once, as they don't really have the tools to assess the situation. Where lack of knowledge about the product originally drove demand, now it accelerates flight.